Wednesday, May 8, 2013

Remedies for the Infringement of Standard Essential Patents Subject to a FRAND Commitment



Following up my posts on Judge Robart’s opinion in Microsoft v. Motorola and on the European Commission’s issuance of a Statement of Objections to Motorola, one of the most important questions in patent and competition law these days is what consequences, if any, should follow when the owner of a standard-essential patent (SEP) that is subject to a commitment to license the SEP on fair, reasonable, and nondiscriminatory (FRAND) terms files suit (or threatens to file suit) for the infringement of the SEP and seeks injunctive relief.  Since the U.S. Supreme Court’s 2006 decision in eBay v. MercExchange, U.S. courts no longer grant prevailing patent owners injunctions as a matter of right but rather weigh the four equitable factors of irreparable harm, adequacy of remedy at law, balance of hardships, and the public interest.  Both Judge Robart in Microsoft v. Motorola and Judge Posner in Apple v. Motorola have expressed the view that, under eBay and as a general rule, a commitment to license an SEP on FRAND terms means that the patent owner cannot obtain an injunction but rather must settle for damages only.  Under U.S. law, those damages can be both compensatory (for past harms suffered) and prospective (for the future use of the patent).  One of the questions on appeal in Apple v. Motorola is whether this view is correct.  I happen to think that it is, because otherwise the risk of patent holdup is too great, though whether the Federal Circuit will agree remains to be seen. If this is the correct view, however, courts deciding such cases will have to determine how to calculate a FRAND royalty.  Most likely, as in Microsoft v. Motorola, courts will determine a FRAND royalty under some version of the Georgia-Pacific willing licensor/willing licensee framework.  As I discussed in an earlier post, I think that Judge Robart largely gets this issue right.  But there are at least three subsidiary issues to consider. 

One relates to the question of timingthat is, as of what date should courts assume the hypothetical negotiations between the willing licensor and willing licensee to take place?  The conventional articulation of Georgia-Pacific states that the hypothetical negotiations occur as of the date the infringement begins, but as I and others have argued in the FRAND context the literal application of this time frame would not avoid the holdup problem where the defendant began using the patented invention after the standard was adopted.  In such cases, economic considerations suggest that to avoid holdup the correct date should be the date on which the standard was adopted.   I am hopeful that the Federal Circuit will agree if it chooses to address this issue in Apple v. Motorola. 

A second issue is whether, as in the conventional application of Georgia-Pacific, courts should try to reconstruct the royalty the parties would have agreed to, ex ante, on the assumption that the patent was valid and infringed.   Again, I argued in my post on Microsoft v. Motorola that in an infringement trial it is economically correct to indulge this counterintuitive assumption in order to avoid a double discounting problem.  However, if a court is trying to reconstruct the royalty outside the context of an infringement action, as in Microsoft v. Motorola itself, it is correct to do as Judge Robart did and consider the probability of validity and infringement as relevant factors in determining the licensing rate.  In other words, a FRAND rate decided pre-patent infringement litigation should be lower than a FRAND rate involving the same patent decided after patent infringement litigation.  Again, some may disagree with me on this, and the result may seem counterintuitive, but I think the analysis is generally sound.

A third issue is whether the FRAND rate for the prospective use of the patent should be increased further yet.  In the post-eBay cases in which U.S. courts have awarded prospective royalties, the Federal Circuit has held that as a general matter the answer is yes, because postjudgment the bargaining position of the parties has changed in favor of the patentee.  Both Mark Lemley and I have argued that this is economic nonsense—the rate should be the same for both pre- and postjudgment royalties—but, for now at least, the rule is what it is.  Nevertheless, I hold out hope that at least in the FRAND context the Federal Circuit will be willing to make an exception, because where the patentee has committed to accept a FRAND royalty a court should not impose what amounts to a super-FRAND royalty for the post-judgment use of the same patent.

In other countries, injunctive relief still often remains the presumptive remedy for patent infringementthough it is interesting to speculate whether this will remain the case indefinitely.   In Europe, for example, article 12 of the EC’s 2004 Enforcement Directive states that members “may provide that, in appropriate cases,” courts may order, in lieu of an injunction, “pecuniary compensation to be paid to the injured party instead of applying the measures provided for in this section if that person acted unintentionally and without negligence, if execution . . . would cause . .  . disproportionate harm and if pecuniary compensation  . . . appears reasonably satisfactory.”   Over the years, there have been a handful of decisions in the U.K. (and at least one in Canada) in which courts have denied prevailing patent owners injunctive relief; and last year, the English Patent Court decided to deny a permanent injunction in an infringement action brought by IPCom against Nokia, reportedly on the ground that the patent in suit was standard-essential.   In addition, as I discuss in my book, based on some limited case law and a 2008 speech by Supreme People’s Court Justice Cao Jianming, there also is reason to believe that Chinese courts have discretion to deny injunctive relief in appropriate cases. 

On the other hand, and notwithstanding the EC Enforcement Directive cited above, courts in Continental Europe still generally appear to view injunctive relief as more or less an entitlement.    With respect to standard-essential patents in particular, however, in the 2009 Orange-Book-Standard case the German Bundesgerichtshof (BGH) (Federal Supreme Court) held that competition law could sometimes obligate the owner of a standard-essential patent to license the patent on FRAND terms.  More specifically, an infringer may not be enjoined if it proves, first, that it “made an offer, ready for acceptance, on contractual conditions, which the patent holder cannot refuse without thereby treating the party seeking a license unequally without good cause as compared with similar enterprises or impeding him inequitably” in violation of German competition law, which forbids a “market-dominant patent holder” from abusing its market-dominant position by refusing “to conclude a contract offered to him on non-obstructive and non-discriminatory terms.”  Second, the infringer must “behave[ ]  as if the patent holder had already accepted his offer” by paying “the consideration that the licensee would be obliged to pay according to a non-discriminatory or non-obstructive licence contract.”  BGH May 6, 2009, GRUR INT. 747, 2009 (Ger.), English translation available at 41 IIC 369-75 (2010).  Under this approach, competition law may provide a means for avoiding a permanent injunction in some class of cases, though hardly in all cases involving SEPs; indeed, in practice so far, it would appear to be the rare case that satisfies Orange-Book-Standard. Anyway, in March 2013, a German court in Duesseldorf referred to the Court of Justice for the European Union (CJEU) the question of whether it is an abuse of dominant position for the owner of an SEP who has made a FRAND commitment to seek an injunction (for discussion, see here); and the same issue may come up in connection with the E.C.’s Statements of Objections against Motorola and an earlier one directed against Samsung.  So it's possible that Orange-Book-Standard will not be the last word on the issue.   

The broader question is whether it is preferable to decide such issues as a matter of patent law or as a matter of competition (antitrust) law.  There may be pros and cons to either approach, and the answer must depend in part on the content of competition law; the European concept of abuse of dominant position has no precise corollary in the U.S.  My own view is that the eBay approach makes sense in that it enables courts to decide whether injunctive relief is appropriate or not on a case-by-case basis, without inquiring into whether competition law also applies to the matter; at the same time, it would not preclude the application of competition law if and when appropriate.  I hope to write about these issues in greater depth in a forthcoming paper.  But it will be interesting to see how the law evolves with respect to these issues in the coming years.

1 comment:

  1. Re the argument that “a RAND royalty calculated in a breach of contract action ought to be lower than a RAND royalty awarded for the very same patent or patents at the conclusion of an infringement action,” what if the patentee seeks to establish validity of the patents as part of the contract action. Should it be allowed to do so? If it can establish validity, should the contract measure of damages be the same as the infringement measure? Addressing validity for multiple patents that may be at issue in SEP litigation may be very resource intensive.

    A similar problem arises in establishing the importance of the patent to the standard. In this case, it seems that no evidence was led on this issue, and Robart J in effect put the burden on the patentee, Motorola, to establish the importance of the patents:

    373. Because of the limited evidence showing the importance of the '724 and '730 Patents to the 802.11 Standard, parties in a hypothetical negotiation would view both patents as providing very minimal technical contribution to data modulation or OFDM.

    See similarly, with other patents, 379, 390, 400. This is notwithstanding that Microsoft is the plaintiff, not Motorola. Do you think this is the right approach?

    ReplyDelete