1. The Journal of Intellectual Property Law & Practice (JIPLP) has two
articles relating to patent royalties this month (volume 9, issue 11, November
2014), both available here.
First, Jeremy Phillips has a short editorial titled The Typical License
Royalty Rate: A Sea of Change. Second, Tilman Müller and
Volkmar Henke have a paper titled Patent enforcement as a violation of
antitrust law: EU Commission decisions in Samsung and Motorola,
which previously appeared at pages 662-65 of the July 2014 issue of the German
publication GRUR Int. under the title Patentdurchsetzung als
Kartellrechtsvertoß. Die Entscheidungen der EU-Kommission in Sachen Samsung
und Motorola, and which I blogged about this past July here.
2.
The Essential
Patent Blog noted recently that the European Commission is seeking public
comments on patents and standards through January 31, 2015. Here
is a link to the Commission's webpage, from which readers may download and
answer questions relating to eight key issues-- among them "What
principles and methods do you find useful in order to apply [the terms
"fair," "reasonable," and "non-discriminatory"]
in practice?", and "How can it be ensured that injunctions based on
standard essential patents are not used to (a) either exclude companies from
implementing a standard or (b) to extract unreasonable, unfair or
discriminatory royalties?"
3.
On September 10, 2014, U.S. Federal Trade Commission Chair Edith Ramirez
delivered a speech
titled Standard Essential Patents and Licensing: An Antitrust
Enforcement Perspective. The speech briefly discusses the FTC's 2013
action relating to Google's acquisition of Motorola Mobility, the European
Commission's investigations of Samsung and Motorola Mobility, and the FTC's
recommendation in its 2011 report The Evolving IP Marketplace: Aligning
Patent Notice and Remedies with Competition that FRAND royalties be
calculated on the basis of a hypothetical negotiation occurring "before
the licensee has made significant investments to implement a technology"
and reflecting the incremental value of the technology in comparison with
alternatives. More interesting, however, are some rather blunt statements
about China:
In contrast to the FTC’s and EC’s approach, media reports indicate that China’s antitrust authorities may be willing to impose liability based solely on the royalty terms that a patent owner demands for a license to its FRAND-encumbered SEPs, as well as royalty demands for licenses for other patents that may not be subject to a voluntary FRAND commitment.
I am seriously concerned by these reports, which suggest an enforcement policy focused on reducing royalty payments for local implementers as a matter of industrial policy, rather than protecting competition and long-run consumer welfare.
The
following week, FTC Commissioner Maureen Ohlhausen echoed these concerns about
China in her speech
titled Antitrust Enforcement in China-What Next?-Second Annual GCR Live
Conference, and suggested that China was taking inspiration from the FTC's
decision (from which she dissented) in Google/Motorola Mobility.
4. William Rooklidge has published an interesting paper titled Infringer's Profits Redux: The Analytical Method of Determining Patent Infringement Reasonable Royalty Damages, in Bloomberg BNA Patent, Trademark & Copyright Law Daily (Nov. 5, 2014), available here behind a paywall. As stated in Lucent Technologies, Inc. v. Gateway, Inc., 580 F.3d 1301, 1325 (Fed. Cir. 2009), as an alternative to the hypothetical negotiation or willing licensor/willing licensee framework for estimating reasonable royalties, U.S. courts sometimes employ an "analytic" approach that “focuses on the infringer's projections of profit for the infringing product.” Mr. Rooklidge argues that, in practice, courts that use this method do not properly take into account what portion of the anticipated profits are attributable to the patent, and do not consider the expected profits as merely a cap on the prospective royalty. Worse yet, in Mr. Rooklidge's analysis, courts sometimes use the infringer's actual profits as a proxy for its anticipated profits and thus effectively restore the remedy of an accounting of infringer's profits, which (though common in many parts of the world, and still available for design patent and other IP infringement in the U.S.) was eliminated from U.S. utility patent law in 1946.
No comments:
Post a Comment