Dr. Peter Meier-Beck is the
presiding judge of the Xth Senate of the German Federal Supreme Court
(Bundesgerichtshof, or BGH). He also has authored several articles on
patent law and remedies, including a few that I cite in my book. A couple of days ago I came across a translation in French of a 2012 article he published in the German law journal Wettbewerb
in Recht und Praxis (WRP), pages 503-08, titled Schadenskompensation bei
der Verletzung gewerblicher Schutzrechte nach dem Durchsetzungsgesetz ("Damages for the Infringement of Industrial Property Rights after the
Enforcement Directive"). The French translation is by the esteemed
French patent litigation firm Véron
et Associés
and appears in the November 2013 issue of the French IP journal Propriété
Industrielle, under the title Allemagne: les dommages-intérêts
pour contrefaçon des droits de propriétê industrielle après
la loi sur l’amélioration du respect des droits de propriété intellectuelle. (This morning my research assistant in Munich sent me a copy of the original German version; so far, however, I've read the French translation and only had time to take a quick look at the German original. If I decide that anything herein needs to be further clarified or amplified after I'd read the German original more carefully, I'll add an update.) Dr. Meier-Beck's thesis
is that the traditional three methods for awarding damages under German
law--lost profits, a reasonable royalty, and an accounting of the infringer's
profits--should, at least after the 2004 E.C. Enforcement Directive, all be interpreted as intended
to provide just compensation to the IP owner. For this reason, all three
should in principle converge. The BGH's 2000 opinion in Gemeinkostenanteil,
which held that in awarding the infringer's profits the court should deduct
only variable costs and not a portion of fixed costs, is in Dr. Meier-Beck's view,
consistent with this principle.
In September I blogged on article by
Adrian Kleinheyer and Henning Hartwig, titled titled Kausalitätsabschlag
und Kontrollüberlegung beim Verletzergewinn: Zugleich Besprechung von
BGH, Urt. v. 24.7.2012-X ZR 51/11-Flaschenträger, published in issue 7 of the
2013 volume of GRUR. I noted there that these two authors took issue with
the BGH's statement in the Flaschenträger case that "Since the
various methods of estimating the damages payable serve to compensate one and
the same damage sustained by the patent proprietor owing to the infringements
committed, as a rule, based on their underlying principle, these methods should
essentially have similar results even where divergences are inevitable owing to
the different parameters underlying each individual calculation" (citing
Klaus-J. Melullis, Zur Ermittlung und zum Ausgleich des Schadens bei
Patentverletzungen, GRUR 2008, 679 (684)). I side with Kleinmeyer
and Hartwig; at least as an economic matter, the convergence principle doesn't make sense to me. To
be sure, if I understand him correctly, Dr. Meier-Beck recognizes that it is a fallacy to assume that the infringer's
profit is the same as the amount the IP owner would have earned, but for the
infringement. He argues instead that economic considerations are not
always paramount, and that damages are a matter of providing "just reparation"; it would be unjust, in his view, to allow the infringer to retain any of the
benefits of infringement. (He draws a distinction between the harm suffered by the rightholder, and the amount due for the reparation of this harm.) Correctly applied, the three methods essentially should lead to consistent results. (The French translation states that "Correctement appliquées, les différentes méthodes doivent donc également mener à des résultats concordants (pour l'essentiel)." The German original reads "Sachgerecht angewandt müssen daher die unterschiedlichen Methoden auch zu (im Wesentlichen) übereinstimmenden Ergebnissen führen.") With
this perspective in mind, courts should restrain themselves from awarding
excessive judgments based on the infringer's profits, but at the same time
should recognize that an award of reasonable royalties may be twice the amount
that would commonly be agreed upon in an arm's-length transaction.
I'm still not convinced that it is a good idea to depart from economic substance and award damages based on more nebulous concerns about "just reparation." Moreover, I think that reasonable royalties, lost profits, and infringers' profits all serve somewhat different purposes that depend on the economic facts of a given case, as I explain in my book.
Lost profits are appropriate when the IP owner's interest lies in exclusion, rather than licensing; reasonable royalties make the most sense when the infringer is a more efficient user of the invention, such that exclusion wasn't in the IP owner's interest, but licensing would have been; and awards of profits, if justified at all, are best rationalized as a means for deterring infringement. On the other hand, I recognize that parties who in theory might seem to deserve a lost profits award might not be able to satisfy proof standards, or might prefer to keep their financial information secret (as Dr. Meier-Beck notes); and that royalties can be thought of as either restitutionary or compensatory. Finally, there is always going to be an element of uncertainty in awarding damages, particularly in systems in which discovery is more limited than in the U.S. Nonetheless, I think that conceiving the three methods as converging is not the right perspective on what, in my view, should be principally an economic matter.
No comments:
Post a Comment