I'll be taking a little hiatus from blogging over the next couple of weeks. If any of my readers happen to be in the Munich area in early July, however, they might be interested in attending the lecture I will be giving at the Max Planck Institute on the evening of July 8 for the the Munich Intellectual Property Law Center Lecture Series. My topic is "The Comparative Law and Economics of Standard Essential Patents and FRAND Royalties." Details can be found here.
Thursday, June 20, 2013
Tuesday, June 18, 2013
Recent French case on invalidation actions
As I mentioned in this post last week, in many countries, including the U.K., Germany, China, and Japan, anyone can initiate an action to invalidate a patent. (I'm not talking here about oppositions, but rather about nullification or invalidation actions which can be commenced after the time for filing an opposition has passed.) As I also discussed, U.S. practice is more restrictive, though not quite as restrictive as it was prior to the Supreme Court's 2007 decision in MedImmune.
French law lies somewhere in between these two models, as I discuss in my book at p.278 n.220. A person may file an action to invalidate a patent if he can demonstrate that the patent is capable of harming him, by reason of either his actual or potential activities. A recent case on point--too recent to make its way into my book--is Sebban v. Barilla France, Cour d'appel de Paris, Mar. 6, 2013, PIBD No. 983, III 1150. Barila sought to invalidate two patents owned by Alain and Claude Sebban. The court of first instance held that Barila had standing and declared one claim of each patent invalid for lack of novelty. The Court of Appeals reversed, stating inter alia that a nullification action may be brought by any person having a direct and personal interest in proceeding (intérêt à agir) in the sense of article 31 of the Code of Civil Procedure; that a competitor may proceed if it has an interest in freeing up a use similar to that of the patented technique; that Barila neither established nor alleged the existence of preparatory acts or serious projects for implementing a technique close to that of the challenged patents; and that the patentees had never invoked an identity, real or supposed, between the patented invention and the object exploited by Barila. The case report in PIBD also includes an editor's note on other cases discussing what sort of an interest suffices, including the Omnipharm case that is mentioned in my book.
Monday, June 17, 2013
Monday miscellany: Some items worth reading
The U.S. Supreme Court's decision on gene patents isn't the only patent-related item in the news these days. From around the web, here are a few recent items relating to patent remedies:
1. Over at PatLit is a write-up on a May 17 decision of the Court of Appeals for England and Wales in Novartis AG v. Hospira UK Ltd., stating the law regarding interim injunctions pending appeal, where the party requesting the injunction was unsuccessful at first instance.
2. At Patently-O and at Essential Patents are write-ups of the June 14 decision of the U.S. Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit in Robert Bosch, LLC v. Pylon Mfg. Corp., holding en banc that the court has jurisdiction to entertain appeals from determinations of patent infringement liability, even though a trial on damages and on willfulness has yet to occur. As I have noted in a previous post, bifurcation is common in many countries, less so in the U.S. There are advantages and disadvantages to both rules.
3. At Kluwer IP is a brief discussion of the CJEU's October 25 decision in Folien Fischer AG v. Ritrama SpA. Fischer (a Swiss company) filed an action in Germany for a negative declaration that its patent licensing practices with respect to Ritrama (an Italian company) did not violate EU competition law. Ritrama then filed an action in Italy, alleging that Fischer was in violation of E.U. competition law. The German court dismissed the action for the negative declaration, on the ground that it lacked jurisdiction under Brussels Regulation article 5(3) (relating to actions in tort) where the party seeking the declaration was trying to establish that no tort had actually occurred. The CJEU reversed, holding that "point (3) of Article 5 of Regulation
No 44/2001 must be interpreted as meaning that an action for a negative
declaration seeking to establish the absence of liability in tort,
delict, or quasi-delict falls within the scope of that provision." It would seem that this decision disposes of one possible means for fending off so-called torpedo actions, for discussion of which see my book at pp. 250-55. Page 255 n.156 referenced the then-pending decision in Folien Fischer.
And this just in: Though not directly related to the subject of patent remedies, the U.S. Supreme Court just held in FTC v. Actavis that so-called reverse payments or pay-for-delay settlements of patent infringement actions between brand-name and generic pharmaceutical companies are not presumptively unlawful, but are to be evaluated under antitrust law's rule of reason. I've written a lot on this issue in the past and will be spending the morning reading the decision, which appears to be 5-3 with Justice Alito recusing himself.
And this just in: Though not directly related to the subject of patent remedies, the U.S. Supreme Court just held in FTC v. Actavis that so-called reverse payments or pay-for-delay settlements of patent infringement actions between brand-name and generic pharmaceutical companies are not presumptively unlawful, but are to be evaluated under antitrust law's rule of reason. I've written a lot on this issue in the past and will be spending the morning reading the decision, which appears to be 5-3 with Justice Alito recusing himself.
Thursday, June 13, 2013
Thursday Miscellany: Some New Works Worth Reading
In the Wall Street Journal this morning is a story about the $2.15 billion settlement of patent infringement litigation between Pfizer and Takeda (plaintiffs) and Teva and Sun (defendant generic drug companies). The damages trial had begun on Monday. See also coverage here.
I've been working my way through a stack of materials on patent remedies, FRAND, and related issues, some of which I have been accumulating since my book came out. Here, in no particular order, are some items worth taking a look at:
I've been working my way through a stack of materials on patent remedies, FRAND, and related issues, some of which I have been accumulating since my book came out. Here, in no particular order, are some items worth taking a look at:
1.
Saisie-Contrefaçon (Pierre Véron ed., 3d ed. 2012). Véron et Associés was
kind enough to send me a copy of their edition of this treatise on the
saisie-contrefaçon, an pretrial order used in France to obtain evidence of
infringement (briefly discussed in my book at p.230). The treatise
provides a wealth of detail on the use of this procedure in various types of
cases, along with statutory and case law annexes. Anyone interested in IP
enforcement in France will want to have this book as a reference. In
French.
2.
Tom Carver, UK Patent Disputes: Damages, China IP, Jan. 2013, available here. A good overview of relevant
legislation and case law in the U.K.
3.
The Exercise of Essential Patents for Standards, 21 IIP Bulletin 1
(2012), available here. This is "an English translation of the summary of a FY2011
Institute of Intellectual Property (IIP) research study report" on issues
relating to standard essential patents (SEPs) in Japan, including whether a
FRAND commitment constitutes a binding contract for the benefit of third
parties and whether SEP owners should be able to obtain injunctions. I
hope that some of the articles summarized, in particular those by Ryuta
Hirashima, Sadao Nagaoka, and Yoshiyuki Tamura, will be at some point be
translated in full.
4.
Marc Grunwald, Der Kartellrechtlichte Zwangslizeneinwand: Muss der
Lizenzangebot einen Kündigungsvorbehalt für den Fall enthalten, dass der
Lizenzsucher das Klagepatent angreift?, Mitt. Heft 11/2012, 492. In
German, obviously. My translation of the title: "The Competition
Law Compulsory License Objection: Must a License Offer Include a
Cancellation Provision in the Event the Prospective Licensee Challenges the
Patent?" The question is whether the Orange-Book-Standard defense
requires the prospective licensee of a standard essential patent to agree not
to challenge the patent. The author argues to the contrary. In
somewhat the same vein, also worth looking at is Daniel Hoppe-Jänisch's
commentary (also in German) following the excerpt from LG Düsseldorf, Decision
of Mar. 21, 2013, 4 b O 104/12, 2013 GRUR-RR 196, 200 (the case referring
questions about the Orange-Book-Standard framework to the CJEU).
5. I haven't read this yet, but
the idea sounds interesting: an article by Jonathan Masur and Anup
Malani, forthcoming in the Georgetown Law Journal, arguing for higher penalties
for the losing party (plaintiff or defendant) in patent litigation.
Professor Masur's guest post on the Written
Description blog summarizes the paper, which can be downloaded from ssrn.
6. Roger G. Brooks & Damien Geradin, Interpreting and Enforcing the Voluntary FRAND Commitment, 9 Int'l J. IT Standards & Standardization Res. 1 (2011), available here, and Dennis W. Carlton & Allan L. Shampine, An Economic Interpretation of FRAND, available on ssrn. Two different and interesting perspectives on how to interpret FRAND commitments made to SSOs.
And this just in: U.S. Supreme Court holds that isolated DNA is not patentable subject matter, cDNA is. Here's the opinion in Association for Molecular Pathology v. Myriad Genetics, Inc.
Tuesday, June 11, 2013
Federal Circuit Affirms Judgment of No Jurisdiction to Consider Declaratory Judgment Action Against Monsanto
On June 10, the Federal Circuit in Organic Seed Growers and Trade v. Monsanto Co. affirmed a
judgment that there was no justiciable "case or controversy" in an
action filed by "a coalition of farmers, seed sellers, and agricultural
organizations" seeking declaratory judgmentsof non-infringement and
invalidity with respect to 23 Monsanto patents relating to technology for
genetically modifying seeds. The plaintiffs expressed concern that they
could be accused of inadvertent infringement if their crops "become
contaminated with transgenic seed."
For those of you who aren't familiar with the
U.S. law of declaratory judgments, here's a little primer. Article III
section 2 of the Constitution states that “The
judicial Power shall extend to all Cases, in Law and Equity, arising under . .
. the Laws of the United States . . . to Controversies to which the United
States shall be a Party . . . [and to Controversies] between Citizens of
different States . . . .” The federal Declaratory Judgment Act, in turn,
states that “In a case of actual controversy within its jurisdiction . .
. any court of the United States, upon the filing of an appropriate pleading,
may declare the rights and other legal relations of any interested
party." In determining whether a federal court may entertain a
petition for declaratory relief, then, the question “’is whether the facts
alleged, under all the circumstances, show that there is a substantial
controversy, between parties having adverse legal interests, of sufficient
immediacy and reality to warrant the issuance of a declaratory
judgment.’” MedImmune, Inc. v. Genentech, Inc., 549 U.S. 118, 127 (2007). So you can't just go into
court and ask the court to declare a patent invalid, as is the practice in some
countries (e.g., the U.K., Germany, Japan, China) in relation to nullification
actions (as described in my book at pp. 212, 278-79, 329, 361). In Organic
Seed Growers, Monsanto had refused the appellants' request for a
written covenant not to sue, but it had referred them "to a statement
posted on its website" stating that "It has never been, nor will it
be Monsanto policy to exercise its patent rights where trace amounts of our
patented seeds or traits are present in farmer’s fields as a result of
inadvertent means." The Federal
Circuit held that "Because Monsanto has made binding assurances
that it will not 'take legal action against growers whose crops might
inadvertently contain traces of Monsanto biotech genes (because, for example,
some transgenic seed or pollen blew onto the grower’s land),' and appellants
have not alleged any circumstances placing them beyond the scope of those
assurances," there was no justiciable case or controversy."
Aside from the interesting questions of
substantive law suggested by the facts, the difficult question from the
standpoint of remedies/procedure is how difficult should it be to challenge
patent validity or request a declaration of noninfringement. One risk of
making it very easy to challenge validity is that it renders patent rights more
vulnerable and hence less valuable; there is a cost to defending even a
nonmeritorious challenge. The obvious drawback to making it difficult to
challenge validity is that you can wind up with lots of invalid patents never
going challenged. Many other factors, including the error rate in granting
patents, the availability (or not) of other avenues for challenging validity
(including oppositions and raising invalidity as a defense in infringement
litigation), and whether the patent validity defense if available operates to
cancel the patent altogether or is merely a personal defense, are also
potentially relevant. Given this complexity and interdependence, I find
it difficult to conceptualize what an optimal system for challenging validity
would look like, but it is an interesting problem.
For more on declaratory judgments of
noninfringement under U.S. and German law, see my post of May 21. For
an interesting paper discussing, among other things, the now-obsolete common
law writ of scire facias, which long ago in the U.K. and the U.S. permitted
anyone to mount a patent validity challenge, look for Mark Lemley's forthcoming
(not yet publicly available, I don't think) article "Why Do Juries Decide
if Patents Are Valid?"
Monday, June 10, 2013
A Simple Economic Model of When Courts Should Award Permanent Injunctive Relief for Patent Infringement, and When They Shouldn’t
I have argued elsewhere that the principal economic
justification for awarding permanent injunctions in patent infringement cases comes
down to information costs: in other
words, that the parties are in a better position than is a court to determine
what the patent is worth in terms of how much it is likely to contribute to the
infringer’s ability to increase profits or reduce costs. (Note that when the infringer is a less efficient
user of the invention than is the patentee, you wouldn’t expect the parties to
reach any agreement. The patentee would
simply exclude the infringer, which is the correct outcome assuming that we
want to preserve the patent incentive.
In such a case, an adequate alternative to an injunction would be a
court-ordered royalty that would exceed the amount the infringer would be
willing to pay. When the infringer is more efficient, you would expect the parties to bargain toward a license following entry of the injunction, if they haven't done so already.) Thus when courts award
ongoing royalties they may generate two costs that otherwise would be
avoided: the adjudication costs incurred
as a result of having to litigate the amount of the royalty, above what would
have been incurred if the court had awarded an injunction instead; and error costs
resulting from the court setting the amount of the royalty too high or too low. Those error costs would take the form of
either unnecessary deadweight loss if the royalty is set higher than what the
parties would have agreed to, or the social costs of whatever consequences follow
from setting the royalty too low and thus potentially undermining the patent
incentive. We can denote adjudication
costs with the letter A and error costs with the letter E.
On the other hand, there is also a social cost to entering
an injunction. One possible cost is that
an injunction will limit access to some product that is necessary to public health
or safety, and it is this cost that might justify compulsory licensing in some
cases, but I will put that matter to one side for now and focus instead on the
cost that is more likely to arise in a broader range of cases, namely patent
holdup. The touchstone of patent holdup
is that the patentee can use an injunction to extract a royalty that reflects not only the ex ante
value of the patent but also the ex post costs that the infringer would face in
trying to design around (or, to put it another way, some of the value of
complementary technologies with which the patented invention interacts). I view this as a social cost because it
results in greater deadweight loss than is necessary to preserve the patent
incentive; the patentee winds up getting a royalty that is higher than the
value of the patent’s contribution to the state of the art. Let’s call the costs arising from patent
holdup H.
If my analysis is correct, then courts should award the
prevailing patentee a permanent injunction when A+ E > H, and they should
deny an injunction when A + E < H.
To be sure, no one can quantify these variables; but I think
we can draw some inferences as to whether A + E is likely to be greater or less
than H in a large number of cases. First,
there are likely to be cases where the cost of holdup is small. A principal example would again be when the patentee
would not agree to any royalty because the patentee is the more efficient user
and therefore prefers exclusion to licensing.
There’s no holdup because the patentee will not be extracting any future
rents from the infringer. Second, while traditionally
some analysts have believed that what I am calling A and E are high, that may
not always be the case. In particular, where
the court is awarding past damages that provide a basis for calculating a
future royalty, A may not be all that significant. While some might express concern that courts
are more likely to undervalue than overvalue the patent (so that error costs
will be potentially large and will undermine the patent incentive), I’m not
sure that’s necessarily right. In cases in
which courts grant compulsory licenses (say, for drugs), that may be a risk,
because the whole point of that type of compulsory licensing is to make the invention available at
a below-market price. If we exclude
those cases from our consideration and focus on more common examples, I’m not
sure there’s any theoretical reason to expect awards systematically to be
biased one way or the other. I suppose that
if infringers can somehow calculate that they will negotiate when a court is
likely to award an overcompensatory remedy and to infringe when it is likely to
award an undercompensatory remedy, self-selection would lead to systematic undercompensation. But that seems to require a good deal of foresight
on the part of infringers, as well a willingness to ignore the high cost of attorney
fees and the risk of enhanced damages if the defendant knowingly infringes. If anything, the risk of overcompensation
might be higher if courts award ongoing royalties based on a higher royalty
rate than they use to calculated damages for past infringement, which (unfortunately)
is the current U.S. practice. Third, courts
can look for indicia of when holdup risk is substantial, based on whether the infringing
product incorporates numerous patents, whether the patented invention would be
easy to design around, and so on.
Thus my own view is that in cases in which holdup risk is
large, courts should generally deny injunctions based on the above
analysis. When holdup risk is not so high,
which I think would be the majority of cases, I’d be willing to assume that A and E are large enough to militate in favor of
injunctive relief, though ultimately I suppose the magnitude of those variables
is an empirical question.
Friday, June 7, 2013
Attorney fee shifting in patent litigation
Section 285 of the U.S.
Patent Act states that courts "in exceptional circumstances may award
reasonable attorney fees to the prevailing party.” Case law establishes that the moving party
must establish exceptional circumstances by clear and convincing evidence;the
district court then determines if fees are appropriate, and if so in what
amount. The amount is reviewed on appeal
under the abuse of discretion standard. Only a limited number of circumstances
justify fee awards in patent cases, however, including “inequitable conduct before the PTO;
litigation misconduct; vexatious, unjustified, and otherwise bad faith
litigation; a frivolous suit or willful infringement.” Wedgetail, Ltd. v. Huddleston Deluxe, Inc.,
576 F.3d 1302, 1304 (Fed. Cir. 2009). As
I discuss in my book (see pp. 209, 276, 328, 360, 370, 372), although
attorneys' fees are not often awarded in China and Taiwan, the limited
availability of attorneys' fees in U.S. law differs from practice in many other
countries (including the European nations, Canada, Australia, and Japan), which
award attorneys' fees to the prevailing party--though often not in the full
amount that the prevailing party actually incurred. In Japan, for example,
parties don't always request fees, and when they are awarded, they often are
set at 10% of the damages recovered rather than based on an hours-worked basis.
Recent proposals, however, may indicate some changes coming
to U.S. law. President Obama's recent recommendations to Congress, for example,
include "providing district courts with more discretion to award
attorney’s fees under 35 USC 285 as a sanction for abusive court filings
(similar to the legal standard that applies in copyright infringement
cases)." On Wednesday, Chief Judge Rader and Professors Colleen
Chien and David Hricik published an op-ed in the New York Times stating that "fees were shifted under Section 285 in only 20 out of nearly 3,000 patent cases filed in 2011," but arguing that judges could and should award fees more frequently. And there are some proposals pending in Congress that might make it easier for courts to award attorneys' fees. The Essential Patents Blog has links to the pending bills.
I've long
suspected that awarding attorneys' fees to the prevailing party, not just in
cases involving abusive or frivolous litigation but as a general policy, would
be a good idea because it would internalize an externality caused either by the
infringement or by the patentee's prosecution of an unsuccessful
suit. As I discuss in my book (see pp. 148-49), however, law and
economics scholars are not of one mind on this issue; according to some of the
models, routine awards of attorneys' fees may decrease the likelihood of
settlement, for example. It would be
great if there were some way to rigorously test the various hypotheses, but the
multiplicity of potentially relevant variables makes this is a daunting task. As the physicist Sean Carroll recently observed
in another context we “make progress by considering all the hypotheses, and
working hard to bring them into confrontation with the data. Use philosophical
considerations all you want to inspire you to come up with new and better
ideas; but it’s reality that ultimately judges them.” In the social sciences and law, unfortunately,
that’s often a tall order.
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)