Today's guest post by Professor Norman Siebrasse of the University of New Brunswick Faculty of Law critiques the Federal Circuit's recent decision in Aqua Shield v. Inter Pool Cover Team, which I blogged about here.
Professor
Cotter and I have a recent paper posted on SSRN arguing that in assessing a
reasonable royalty, the hypothetical negotiation should be assumed to take
place ex ante, but with the full benefit of all ex post information. We call
this the “contingent ex ante” approach to distinguish it from the “pure ex
ante” approach, in which only ex ante information (with some exceptions) can be
considered in the hypothetical negotiation. It was therefore disappointing to
see the Federal Circuit embrace the pure ex ante approach in its recent
decision in Aqua Shield v. Inter Pool Cover Team (available here, summary post here). Aqua
Shield’s emphasis on the pure ex ante approach is puzzling as well as
disappointing. On the facts, the only admissible evidence relevant to
the royalty was ex post information, in particular, the infringer’s actual
profits. Even under the pure ex ante approach, as was specifically affirmed in Aqua Shield, ex post information may be
considered as evidence of what the parties would have believed ex ante. So, in
this case, actual profits may be considered as evidence of expected profits.
The two approaches only differ when there is conflicting evidence as to both
expected and actual profits (or other relevant information). It is therefore
unclear why the Federal Circuit emphasized the need to use the pure ex ante
approach, given that it explicitly endorsed the use of ex post information.
Moreover, even on the pure ex ante approach and even in light of the Federal
Court’s decision, it is difficult to understand how the District Court erred.
Aqua Shield’s ‘160 patent relates to enclosures designed to
cover pools or create sun rooms. The district court granted summary judgment
against Inter Pool Cover Team (IPC) on infringement and validity. These
judgments were not appealed (except regarding one of IPC’s models). The
district court then conducted a two-day bench trial on remedies. In the
original damages opinion, which I was unable to dig up, the district court held
that Aqua Shield had failed to prove lost-profit damages. That was not
appealed. The district court also refused a reasonable royalty, on the basis
that there was not sufficient evidence to establish the reasonable royalty
rate; while there was some evidence relevant to the Geogia-Pacific factors that indicated that the royalty should be
adjusted upwards, there wasn’t sufficient evidence to determine the initial
royalty rate that would then be adjusted. On a motion before the district court
to alter the judgment, 2013 WL 6410975, the patentee argued that in determining
a reasonable royalty the court should have considered (1) licensing
negotiations that the parties conducted in 2009; (2) the inventor’s evidence;
and (3) the infringer’s actual profits on infringing sales. The district court
rejected the first two, on the basis that settlement negotiations conducted
during litigation cannot be used to determine a reasonable royalty and the
negotiations were not in any event confined to licensing of the invention at
issue, and because the inventor’s evidence was not credible. These holdings
were not challenged on appeal (Fed Cir slip op 10). The district court
acknowledged that the infringer’s profit was admissible evidence which it
wrongly failed to consider. Thus the only evidence on the reasonable
royalty was the infringer’s actual profits. The district court went on to award
reasonable royalty damages of 8% of the infringer’s net profits on infringing
sales.
On appeal,
the Federal Circuit emphasized what we have called the pure ex ante approach –
“anticipated incremental profits
under the hypothesized conditions are conceptually central to constraining the
royalty negotiation” (slip op 10, emphasis added) – but it also acknowledged
that “[e]vidence of the infringer’s actual profits generally is admissible as
probative of his anticipated profits” (ibid).
Thus the district court did not err in considering the evidence of actual
profits.
The error,
according to the Federal Circuit, lay in how that profit evidence was used:
[The district court] did err in treating the profits IPC actually earned during the period of infringement as a royalty cap. That treatment incorrectly replaces the hypothetical inquiry into what the parties would have anticipated, looking forward when negotiating, with a backward-looking inquiry into what turned out to have happened.
Under either
the pure or contingent ex ante approach it is permissible to use the
infringer’s anticipated incremental
profits as a cap on the royalty, because the infringer’s maximum willingness to
pay is set by the difference between the maximum profit available from the use
of the invention and that available using the best non-infringing alternative:
see eg Grain Processing 185 F.3d
1341, 1350-51 (Fed. Cir. 1999). It appears from the available opinions, namely
those of the Federal Circuit and the district court’s opinion on
reconsideration, there was no direct evidence at all of the anticipated
profits; thus the actual profits were the only admissible evidence of
the anticipated profits. It is true that the district court used the actual
profits as a cap, but it did so expressly on the basis of the pure ex ante
approach (slip op 4, 5):
Although a hypothetical license requires the royalty to be determined in light of anticipated profits when the infringement began, courts have held that evidence of subsequent actual profits is relevant to forming a judgment as to anticipated profits.
Considering [the benefits of the invention], while still allowing Defendants a profit on infringing sales, requires the Court to use its best ability to estimate what Defendants would have likely paid for the patented design.
The district
court was evidently using the actual profits as evidence of the anticipated
profits, and then using the anticipated profits as a cap on the royalty. This
is entirely consistent with the pure ex ante approach.
Now, the
infringer’s profits should not be used as a cap on the royalty when the
infringer is a particularly inefficient producer. As the Federal Circuit
explained:
An especially inefficient infringer—e.g., one operating with needlessly high costs, wasteful practices, or poor management—is not entitled to an especially low royalty rate simply because that is all it can afford to pay without forfeiting or unduly limiting its profit if it uses the patented technology rather than alternatives.
As noted, it
is the infringer’s anticipated incremental profits – that is, the
difference between its profits using the invention and using the best
alternative – which sets the cap on the royalty. If the invention is better
than the alternatives, the infringer’s incremental profits will be positive
regardless of how inefficient the infringer might be, and a reasonable split of
those incremental profits might well result in negative accounting profits. But
on the facts, the Federal Circuit’s reference to an inefficient infringer is
puzzling. There was no indication that the defendant in this case was particularly
inefficient, and the district court explicitly considered the incremental value
of the invention: “In a hypothetical negotiation, the Court finds Defendants
would not have paid more [than 8% of net profits] for the license because they
would have likely gone without the benefits of the '160 Patent and designed
around it, as they have done now.” Again, it is difficult to see what is wrong
with this analysis.
The Federal Circuit
also held that “The district court’s analysis also incorrectly replaces the
inquiry into the parties’ anticipation of what profits would be earned if a royalty (of amounts being negotiated)
were to be paid with an inquiry into what profits were earned when IPC was charging prices without accounting for any
royalty” (original emphasis), explaining that “[t]he infringer’s selling
price can be raised if necessary to accommodate a higher royalty rate.”
Certainly, if an infringer is cutting prices to the bone, in part by avoiding
paying a royalty, then positive accounting profits might well turn negative
once a reasonable royalty is factored in. It would be wrong to use the
infringer’s accounting profits (as opposed to its incremental profits) as a cap
in such circumstances. The Federal Circuit stated that “On the record before
us, we conclude that the district court committed [this error]” (slip op 11).
Again, this is a puzzling statement. It is true, as mentioned above, that the
district court allowed the defendants a profit on infringing sales, and this
was evidently accounting profits, but the actual royalty was only 8% of net
profits. An 8% royalty isn't close enough to the entire profit for the question
of whether the district court wrongly thought it was bound to stay under 100%
to be at issue. This contrasts with, for example, Golight, Inc. v. Wal-Mart Stores, Inc., 355 F.3d 1327, 1338
(Fed.Cir.2004), in which the Federal Circuit rejected the infringer’s complaint
that the reasonable royalty awarded by the district court was unreasonable as a
matter of law because it would have resulted in the infringer selling the
product below cost. More importantly, the district court never invoked the
infringer’s profits as a cap. While it did refer to the need to allow the
defendants a profit on infringing sales, which may indeed be an error in some
circumstances, as we have seen the court expressly held that if the royalty had
been any higher the defendants “would have likely gone without the benefits of
the '160 Patent and designed around it, as they have done now.” In other words,
the cap is not the infringer’s accounting profits, but rather the incremental
profit due to the invention.
Since I am
writing without the benefit of the complete record, it may be that there is
something else in the record which supports the Federal Circuit’s critique, but
as it stands, the Federal Circuit’s decision is more puzzling than
enlightening. If there is any error in the district court’s decision, it lay in
using accounting profits rather than incremental profits as a cap on the
royalty. That would be an error on the contingent ex ante approach just as much
as on the pure ex ante approach. Consequently, while Aqua Shield explicitly embraces the pure ex ante approach, it is
not particularly strong authority for that approach, as the holding on that
point is purely dicta. When the only evidence is ex post evidence, as in this
case, the contingent and pure ex ante approaches will come to the same
conclusion, whatever other errors the court below might (or might not) have
made.
No comments:
Post a Comment