I have previously mentioned my involvement, along with several other scholars
from around the world, in the International Patent Remedies for Complex
Products (INPRECOMP) project. (INPRECOMP began as a joint venture between
the Center for Law, Science and Innovation (CLSI) at Arizona State University's
Sandra Day O'Connor College of Law and the Dickson Poon School of Law at King's
College London, and is primarily funded by a gift to CLSI from Intel.)
The manuscript of our edited volume, Patent Remedies and Complex Products: Toward a Global Consensus (Brad Biddle, Jorge L. Contreras, Brian J. Love & Norman V. Siebrasse eds.) is in the hands
of Cambridge University Press, and should be available in hardcover sometime in the coming months. I mention this project again today because the Introduction to the volume is now, at long last, available on ssrn, along with all of the other chapters. And I really do recommend reading the Introduction, which provides a useful framework for understanding the assumptions underlying the rest of the book.
Here are links to each of the chapters, followed by the abstract:
This introductory chapter to the forthcoming book Patent Remedies and
Complex Products: Toward a Global Consensus describes how innovative
companies routinely bring products to market that implicate tens or even
hundreds of thousands of individual patents issued by patent offices
across the globe, and identifies a number of challenging questions with
respect to how the law should value patents and provide remedies for
their infringement in this context. For example, how should courts and,
where applicable, juries calculate damages for infringement of one
patent out of the thousands of (often complementary) inventions
incorporated in a device? How can courts and juries tell if one feature
among hundreds drove the sale of the entire product? Should patent law
take into consideration that it might not be possible, let alone cost
effective, for a product manufacturer in a fast-moving field to license
all of the thousands of patents embodied in its product, even prior to
beginning development? Should an injunction be granted to prevent the
use of a patented technology that covers a minor feature of a complex
product, when the effect of the injunction would be to keep the entire
product itself off the market? How (if at all) can the risks of patent
holdup be reduced without generating substantial error costs or other
unintended negative consequences? This chapter describes the broader
goals of the book - to begin to addressing these questions
systematically by setting forth both the current state of the law and an
agenda for future research - and identifies a set of foundational
premises applicable across all of the book's chapters.
Chapter
1: Reasonable Royalties (coauthored by Thomas F. Cotter, John M.
Golden, Oskar Liivak, Brian J. Love, Norman Siebrasse, Masabumi Suzuki, and David
O. Taylor):
This
chapter (1) describes the current state of, and normative basis for, the law of
reasonable royalties among the leading jurisdictions for patent infringement
litigation, as well as the principal arguments for and against various
practices relating to the calculation of reasonable royalties; and (2) for each
of the major issues discussed, provides one or more recommendations. The
chapter’s principal recommendation is that, when applying a “bottom-up”
approach to estimating reasonable royalties, courts should replace the
Georgia-Pacific factors (and analogous factors used outside the United States)
with a smaller list of considerations, specifically (1) calculating the
incremental value of the invention and dividing it appropriately between the
parties; (2) assessing market evidence, such as comparable licenses; and (3)
where feasible and cost-justified, using each of these first two considerations
as a “check” on the accuracy of the other.
This
book chapter addresses two types of monetary remedies for patent infringement:
(1) recovery of the patentee’s lost profits and (2) disgorgement of the
infringer’s profits. Both remedies make a comparison between what actually
happened and a hypothetical “but for” world in which no infringement occurred.
But the two remedies have substantially different objectives: lost profits are
intended to compensate the patentee by restoring it to the position it would
have occupied absent infringement, while disgorgement may serve other purposes,
including deterrence, recapturing wrongful gains, and encouraging ex ante
licensing of patented technology.
Part II
addresses several key issues regarding lost profits awards, including the
availability and standard of proof, the role of non-infringing alternatives,
potential recovery for the sale of related but unpatented goods, whether and
how to apportion lost profits awards for complex products, and potential
recovery for other infringement-related harms. Part III describes the
justifications for, and availability of, the disgorgement (accounting) remedy
in major patent systems and, additionally, analyzes a number of questions
related to calculating such awards. In both sections, we make recommendations
and identify areas for further research.
Chapter
3: Enhanced Damages, Litigation Cost Recovery, and Interest
(coauthored by Colleen V. Chien, Jorge L. Contreras, Thomas F. Cotter, Brian J.
Love, Christopher B. Seaman, and Norman Siebrasse):
This
chapter discusses the law and policy of monetary awards—including exemplary
damages and litigation cost recoveries—that go beyond the compensatory damages
to which prevailing parties in patent litigation are normally entitled. Up to
treble damages are authorized in the United States for knowing infringement,
but attorney fees are awarded only in exceptional cases. The rest of the world
tends towards the opposite: attorney fees are awarded as a matter of course,
but punitive damages are generally prohibited as against public policy. In this
chapter we discuss the theory, law, and policy of enhanced damages and attorney
fee awards in the U.S., Europe, and Asia. While the availability of enhanced
damages and fees can bring accused infringers that might otherwise “holdout” to
the table, care must also be taken to ensure that it does not discourage
productive learning from patents or challenges to overbroad and vague patents.
Rather than endorsing any single set of doctrinal rules, we recommend further
research into a number of unanswered questions about current and potential
future configurations, in order to inform future policy-making.
Chapter 4: Injunctive
Relief (coauthored by Norman Siebrasse, Rafał Sikorski, Jorge L.
Contreras, Thomas F. Cotter, John M. Golden, Sang Jo Jong, Brian J. Love, and
David O. Taylor):
Patent
systems commonly empower courts to order accused or adjudged infringers to
refrain from continuing infringing conduct in the future. Some patentees file
suit for the primary purpose of obtaining and enforcing an injunction against
infringement by a competitor, and even in cases in which the patentee is
willing to license an invention to an accused infringer for an agreed price,
the indirect monetary value of an injunction against future infringement can
dwarf the amount a finder of fact is likely to award as compensation for past
infringement. In some of these cases, an injunction, if granted, would impose
costs on accused infringers or third parties that go well beyond the more
intrinsic value of the patented technology. This chapter explores the theory
behind injunctive relief in patent cases, surveys the availability of this
remedy in major patent systems, and suggests a general framework for courts to
use when deciding whether injunctive relief is appropriate in individual cases.
Chapter
5: The Effect of FRAND Commitments on Patent Remedies (coauthored by
Jorge L. Contreras, Thomas F. Cotter, Sang Jo Jong, Brian J. Love, Nicolas
Petit, Peter Georg Picht, Norman Siebrasse, Rafał Sikorski, Masabumi Suzuki,
and Jacques de Werra):
This
chapter addresses a special category of cases in which an asserted patent is,
or has been declared to be, essential to the implementation of a
collaboratively-developed voluntary consensus standard, and the holder of that
patent has agreed to license it to implementers of the standard on terms that
are fair, reasonable and non-discriminatory (FRAND). In this chapter, we
explore how the existence of such a FRAND commitment may affect a patent
holder’s entitlement to monetary damages and injunctive relief. In addition to
issues of patent law, remedies law and contract law, we consider the effect of
competition law on this issue.
Chapter
6: The Effect of Competition Law on Patent Remedies (coauthored by
Alison Jones and Renato Nazzini):
Although
competition law and IP law probably pursue complementary goals, competition
laws can (i) affect remedies available for patent infringement; and/or
otherwise (ii) limit the conduct of patentees, particularly when transferring
or licensing their patents. This chapter discusses the cases in which tensions
between the protection of patents in complex products and the competition laws
have arisen or may arise, particularly as regards the ability of owners of
standard essential patents (SEPs) to monetise their patents either by seeking
an injunction against implementers or by refusing to grant licences complying
with previously given commitments—generally, commitments to license on fair,
reasonable and nondiscriminatory (FRAND) terms. This chapter also examines
potential competition law constraints on the pricing of patent licences, other
licensing terms, multi-level licensing and level discrimination, patent pools,
sale of patent portfolios and patent acquisitions.
Chapter
7: Holdup, Holdout and Royalty Stacking: A Review of the Literature
(authored by Norman Siebrasse):
This
article provides a critical review of the theoretical and empirical literature
on holdup, holdout, and royalty stacking, as they relate to remedies for patent
infringement.